SciELO - Scientific Electronic Library Online

 
vol.16 número1PRESENTACIÓNInversión pública en Bolivia y su incidencia en el crecimiento económico: un análisis desde la perspectiva espacial índice de autoresíndice de materiabúsqueda de artículos
Home Pagelista alfabética de revistas  

Servicios Personalizados

Articulo

Indicadores

    Links relacionados

    • No hay articulos citadosCitado por SciELO
    • No hay articulos similaresSimilares en SciELO

    Bookmark

    Revista de Análisis del Banco Central de Bolivia

    versión impresa ISSN 2304-8875

    Revista de Análisis v.16 n.1 La Paz ene. 2012

     

    ARTÍCULO

     

    ¿Cuán plural es la economía plural de Bolivia?

    Construyendo un indicador de economía plural con conjuntos difusos

     

    How plural isthe plural economy of Bolivia

    Constructing a plural economy indicator with fuzzy sots

     

     

    Rolando Gonzales Martínez*

     

     


    Abstract

    An indicator that measures the compliance with the constitutional principies of a plural economy is proposed. An inference system based on fuzzy sets was used to calcúlate the indicator. The fuzzy system summarizes the principies of income redistribution and environmental sustainability into an overall measure of plural economy that allows to objectively judge the change towards a plural economy in Bolivia.

    JEL Classification: C02, P40
    Keywords:               Plural economy indicator, fuzzy sets


    Resumen

    Se propone un indicador que mide el cumplimiento de los principios constitucionales de una economía plural. Para calcular el indicador se usó un sistema de inferencia basado en conjuntos difusos. El sistema difuso resume los principios de la redistribución del ingreso y la sostenibilidad ambiental en una medida global de economía plural que permite juzgar objetivamente el cambio hacia una economía plural en Bolivia.

    Clasificación JEL: C02, P40
    Palabras clave: indicador de economía plural, conjuntos difusos


     

     

    I. Introduction

    As part of a series of changes of the economic model of Bolivia, the government of this country enacted in 2009 a new State Constitution with the principies of a plural economy. According to this new Constitution, the plural economy of Bolivia comprises different forms of economic organization and it is based on the principies of complementariness, reciprocity, solidarity, redistribution, equity, legal certainty, sustainability equilibrium, justice and transparency1

    Antagonistic political parties take different positions about the change to a plural economy in Bolivia. Opposite parties untiringly argüe about the existence of this change, and they eventually linktheirdiscussion to the principies of the Bolivian plural economy, because if these principies were not met, then it would not be easy to claim a shift towards a more pluralistic economy. Being the principies of a plural economy (henceforth, PPE) vague concepts, any verbal discussion about the compliance with the principies would be subjective and ultimately unproductive. A more scientific approach is to use mathematical tools to objectively measure the degree of compliance with these principies. In this sense, this paper proposes a mathematical indicatorof the plurality of an economy based on fuzzy sets. This indicator can be used to objectively measure the degree of compliance with the PPE, and thus assert the existence of a change to a plural economy in Bolivia.

    Since the purpose of this paper is to make a methodological contribution, and in orderto keep a simple exposition of the techniques, only two of the ten principies were modeled. A complete analysis of the ten PPE would require a full elicitation of 30 fuzzy membership functions and the plural economy indicator would be a 11-polytope (defined in a 11-dimensional hypercube). Due to this, visualizing the plural economy indicator would not be as straightforward as in the Figure 4 of this paper.

    Section II offers some background on the issues behind the concept of a plural economy and their relationship with fuzzy logic. The methods to construct the plural economy indicator are described in section III. Section IV contains the results of the indicator, and Section V concludes.

    MATLAB codes which compute the plural economy indicator and replícate the empirical work reported in this paper are available upon request.

     

    II. Background

    A theoretical approach to the understanding of a 'plural economy' appears to precede the more subtle linguistic characterization of a plural economy contained in the Bolivian new State Constitution of 2009. The Bolivian concept of a 'plural economy' seems to have its roots in the economic theory of welfare pluralista or mixed economy of welfare that highlights the role of the nonprofit sector in welfare and claims that a balanced social economy must be beyond the so-called 'market fundamentalism of neoclassical economics'. According to this approach, welfare is provided by different societal actors, e.g. the government, prívate sources or social cooperatives. See, ínter alia, Evers and Laville (2004), Heitzmann (2006), Stiglitz (2009), Bresser-Pereira (2010) or Etxezarreta and Bakaikoa (2011).

    In Bolivia, the implementation of a plural economy starts in 2006, when a left-wing government changed the Bolivian economic structure in a way that sought to oppose to the so-called neoliberal economic structure. In this alternative model, the economy is comprised by the interaction of social, communitary, prívate, and State economic structures (Pardo, 2009), and the State is conceptualized as the leader in the strategic sectors that deal with the generation and distribution of wealth (García, 2011). Nevertheless, the concept of'plural economy' emerges officially from the new State Constitution of Bolivia enacted in 2009. According to this new Constitution, a plural economy is based on the principies of complementaríness, reciprocity, solidarity, redistribution, equity legal certainty sustainability equilibriumjustice, and transparency. Evidently, these principies are linguistic concepts that contain ambiguities. Thus, policy reasoning with such imprecise concepts may not be clear and obvious, but rather fuzzy.

    Fuzzy logic can be defined as a precise logic of imprecisión and an approximate reasoning, with high power of precisiation2, of what is semantically imprecise (Zadeh, 2008).3 Fuzzy sets, being mathematical tools to handle linguistic variables, are ideal for constructing objective indicators to condense polymorphous concepts. This is why fuzzy logic is often used to construct socioeconomic indicators that measure, ínter alia, bankruptcy, well-being, contamination risk, sustainability, market bidding adjustments or stock market fluctuations. Óstermark (1999) for example, developed an inference system for bankrupt firms, based on fuzzy multigroup classification. Chiappero (2000) tried to make some progress towards the possibility of realizing a multidimensional assessment of Amartya Sen's concept of well-being with the use of fuzzy sets theory. In Castignani et al. (2004), pesticide contamination risk was calculated with a fuzzy logic indicator and the economic costs were assessed by gross margin differences among farm typologies. Phillis and Andriantiatsaholiniaina (2001) used fuzzy logic to construct an inference system that takes ecological (land, water, air, and biodiversity) and human (economical, social, educational, and political) inputs, and then combined these with the aid of fuzzy logic to provide an overall measure of the degree of sustainability of the system under examination (see also Andriantiatsaholiniaina et al., 2004). He et al. (2006) employed heuristic fuzzy rules to emulate the reasoning of artificial agents that dynamically adjust its bidding behaviorto effectively respond to changes in the supply and demand of a marketplace. Finally, with a self-organized fuzzy neural network, Bollen et al. (2011) used the twitter mood to predict the stock market, using the Dow Jones Industrial Average index.4 In this study, the PPE are used as inputs of the fuzzy system, thus offering the possibility of obtaining an overall (numerical) indicator that summarizes the degree of compliance with the welfare pluralism of the principies of a plural economy.

     

    III. Methods5

    Let x be an economic indicator that measures a PPE. This and other n-indicators x1 ... ,xn can be summarized into a single plural economy indicator with an inference system based on fuzzy sets. In this system, a 1 x n vector with valúes of the n-economic indicators is placed into input membership functions. Based on a set of rules, these input functions map the input indicators to an output membership function. The output function translates through fuzzy sets the verbal degree of compliance with the PPE to a numerical indicator bounded between 0 and 1.

    III.1. Fuzzy sets

    Let A denote a set, x the element of any set and U the universal set of all objects under consideration. To define a fuzzy set is necessary to define the characteristic function of a set.

    Definition 1 Characteristic function (membership function). The characteristic function A (x) of a set A C U is a membership rule that characterizes the elements (members) of a set, taking only two valúes 0 and 1, indicating whether or not x U is a member of A:

    As A(x) {0,1}, the characteristic function only indicates if an element belongs or not belongs to A. Fuzzy sets unstrain this crisp membership rule.

    Definition 2 Fuzzy sets. Let A be a classical set ofthe universe U. A fuzzy set ¡s defined by a set of ordered pairs (a binary relation),

    where A (x) is a membership function that specifies the degree to which any element x in A belongs to the fuzzy set , and it ties each element x in Ato a real number in the interval [0,1].

    Fuzzy sets allow to measure numerically the degree of membership to the set A, because in contrast to the function A(x) {0,1}, the membership function of a fuzzy set A(x) is continuous between 0 and 1.

    III.2. Membership functions

    A spline-based z-function, a s-function and a gaussian function can be used as input membership functions. The parameters of the spline-based z-function z (x;1,2),

    and the spline-based s-function s (x; w v ,w2),

    can be calibrated to model the bounds of the economic indicators. The parameters , of the Gaussian function g (x; , )

    can be estimated with historical data of economic indicators, in order to measure the average of the indicators and the spread around this average.

    For the output of the inference system, a trapezoidal function trap (x;1,2,3,4)

    models the non-compliance and the full compliance with the PPE, and a triangular function tri (x; 1 ,2,3 ,4),

    models the middle compliance. Intuitively, these membership functions allow to transíate linguistic vague concepts as "high income inequality" to objective, continuous, and numerical valúes forthe PPE.

    III.3. Rules and thefuzzy indicator qf a plural economy

    The inference system follows Mamdani rules,

    where i, i = 1,.., m, are linguistic bounds defined in the context of the previous fuzzy membership functions and = {1,..., 1} is the expected output.

    The plural economy indicator is the output space [0,1] of the fuzzy inference system. A single valué i of the indicator is calculated after introducing a vector , with valúes of the economic indicators x1...,xn.

    An output valué of i= 1 indicates a full compliance with the principies of a plural economy, and a valué of i= 0 means non-compliance with these principies. Because fuzzy sets are continuous in [0, 1], valúes among (0,1) will indícate a different degree of compliance with the PPE: a valué of i. close to one, indicates a high degree of compliance with the PPE (in general as i1), while valúes of 6. cióse to zero indícate relative non-compliance with these principies (in general asi 0).

     

    IV. Results

    This section calibrates the membership functions and the rules of the inference system that allow to calcúlate the plural economy indicator.

    It is wise to state at the outset that a proper indicator of plurality should consider both the constitutional PPE and the different forms of economic organization in a plural economy. Nevertheless, in order to keep a simple, clear, illustrative, and understandable explanation of the model, only two of the ten constitutional PPE are considered: redistribution and sustainability. (See also the discussion about the dimensionality of the indicator in the introduction of this paper.)

    The study relates the principie oí redistribution to income redistribution because according to the new State Constitution the development in Bolivia will be assured through an equitable redistribution of economic surplus. The principie of sustainability, on the other hand, is related to the concept of environmental sustainability .

    IV.1. Ccdibration ofthe input membership functions

    The Gini coefficient was used to measure the principie of redistribution. The Environmental Sustainability índex (henceforth, ES) is used as the indicator of sustainability.

    The Gini coefficient is an economic indicator of income redistribution. This index is the most commonly used measure of inequality and takes valúes between 0 and 100, with zero interpreted as no inequality (Litchfield, 1999). On the other hand, ES benchmarks the ability of nations to protect the environment over the next several decades, by integrating data sets that track natural resource endowments, past and present pollution levéis, environmental management efforts, and the capacity of a society to improve its environmental performance. The range of the ES indicator is also between [0; 100], but in this case the higher a country's ES index, the better positioned it is to maintain favorable environmental conditions into the future. See Esty et al. (2005)fordetails.

    Figure 1 shows the histogram of the Gini index based on the data from the World Bank for all the countries in the world between the years 2005-2006. This figure also displays the histogram of the ES index for the year2005, based on data of 146 countries around the world.

    The world's average Gini index in the year 2005 was 42,96 (with a standard deviation of 8,76), and the world's average sustainability index in the same year was 49,88 (with a standard deviation of 8,48). These historical valúes of r = 42,96 and r = 8,76 were used to calíbrate the parameters of the Gaussian membership function g (x;r, r) which models middling income redistribution (Table 1 and Figure 2). The values s= 49,8 ands= 8,48 of the ES index were used to calíbrate the membership function of middling environmental sustainability (Table 2 and Figure 2).

    Table 1: CALIBRATION OF MEMBERSHIP FUNCTIONS: REDISTRIBUTION

     

    Table 2: CALIBRATION OF MEMBERSHIP FUNCTIONS: SUSTAINABILITY

     

    Figure 1: ECONOMIC INDICATORS OF REDISTRIBUTION AND SUSTAINABILITY

     

    Figure 2: MEMBERSHIP FUNCTIONS

    The function z (x; r1 , r2) with r1 = 0 and r2 = 100 was used to model the equality in the redistribution of income, and the function s (x;wr1 ,ur2) with wr1 = 0; and wr2 = 100 was used to model the inequality in the income redistribution. Being z (•) a decreasing function, as z (•) 0, it signáis an ideal situation of equity in the income redistribution. Since s (•) is an increasing function, as s (•) 100, it characterizes more inequality in the redistribution of income (Figure 2).

    The input membership functions of the sustainability index were also an s-function s (x; ws1; ws2) and a z-function z (x; s1 , s2 )with parameters w = 0, ws2 = 100, s1 = 0, s2 = 100. In this case the s-function models the environmental sustainability improvement and the z-function models the worsening of the index.

    IV.2. Mamdani rules, fuzzy inference system and output membership function

    Let x1 denote the Gini index and x2 the ES indicator. The Mamdani rules of the plural economy inference system were:

    •   IF (x1 indicates unequal redistributiorí) AND (x2 indicates unsustainability) THEN ( indicates a non-plural economy);

    •   IF (x1 indicates middling redistributiorí) AND (x2 indicates sustainability) THEN ( indicates a middling plural economy);

    •   IF (x1 indicates middling redistributiorí) AND (x2 indicates middling sustainability) THEN ( indicates a middling plural economy);

    •   IF (x1 indicates an unequalredistributiorí) AND (x2 indicates middling sustainability) THEN ( indicates a middling plural economy);

    •   IF (jtj indicates an equal redistributiorí) AND (x2 indicates sustainability) THEN (© indicates a plural economy),

    being the plural economy indicator. Fuzzy sets were used to transíate the linguistic rules into a quantitative economic indicator, using trapezoidal and triangular output functions to measure the degree of compliance with the PPE.

    The valúes of 11 = 0, 12 = 0,5 13 = 0,20, 14 = 0,50 of the output function trap (x; 11, 12, 13, 14) depict a situation of a non-plural economy between 0 and 0,20, and as trap (•) linearly approaches 0,50 reaches a middling plural economy. The trapezoidal function trap (x; 21, 22 ,23 ,24) with 21 = 0,50,22 = 0,80, 23 = 1, 24 = 1 starts at a middle state of plural economy and piecewise linearly approaches 1 with progressive enhancements. The triangular function tri (x; 1 , 2 , 3) with 1 = 0,25, 2 = 0,50; 3 = 0,75 models the middle state of the indicator ranging between a complete plural economy and a non-plural economy (Table 3, Figure 2).

    Table 3: CALIBRATION OF MEMBERSHIP FUNCTIONS:
    PLURAL ECONOMY

    The complete inference system used to calcúlate the plural economy indicator can be appreciated in Figure 3. The diagram shows that if a vector , with valúes of the indicators of redistribution and sustainability were introduced into the membership functions, the inference system would output a scalar iwith a valué of the plural economy indicator.

    Figure 3: INFERENCE SYSTEM

    IV3. The plural economy indicator

    Figure 4 shows a surface view of the plural economy indicator , as a function of the redistribution and sustainability indicators previously discussed. Also, a bivariate projection of the surface is depicted on Figure 5.

    Figure 4: SURFACE-VIEW OF THE PLURAL ECONOMY INDICATOR ()

    Figure 5: BIVARIATE PROJECTIONS

    As it can be seen, the plural economy indicator is a non-linear decreasing function of the redistribution indicator, i.e. indicates a high degree of plurality when the redistribution is cióse to 0 (expressing total equality) and the indicator falls to zero as the valué of redistribution approaches a valué of 100 (maximal inequality).

    At the same time, the plurality indicator is an increasing nonlinear function ofthe indicator of sustainability. Ifthe indicator of sustainability increases (signaling more environmental sustainability) then increases too, being sustainability an ideal principie of a plural economy.

    IV.4. Numerical examples ofthe plural economy indicator

    As examples of using the plural economy indicator , vectors with real and hypothetical valúes ofthe Gini indexand the ES indexwill be used in the inference system for a plural economy.

    In the year 2005, before the socialist movement led the government in Bolivia, the Gini index of Bolivia was equal to 58, and the ES indicator of sustainability was equal to 59,5. Using these valúes, a vector 1= [58 59,5] was introduced into the inference system, and the output valué of the plural economy indicator was equal to 1 = 0,5065 (Table 4). The indicator suggests, as expected, a poor compliance with the principies of a plural economy in the year 2005.

    Table 4: PLURAL ECONOMY INDICATOR


    The value of 11 = 58 is the Gini Índex of Bolivia for the year
    2005 (source: TheWorld Bank) and the valué of 12 = 59,5 is
    the valué of the Environmental Sustainability Index for Bolivia
    for the year 2005 (source: Yale Center for Environmental Law
    and Policy, Yale University, and Center for International Earth
    Science Information Network, Columbia University). No
    information is available for the ES after the year 2005, and
    the valué of the Gini Índex in the year 2007 for Bolivia was
    used in 21 =57

    No information of the ES index is available after the year 2005, and the most recent information of the Gini índex in Bolivia dates the year 2007. In this year, the Gini index was equal to 57. Assuming no change in the ES index between these years, a second vector 2 = [57 59,5] yields an indicator of plurality equal 2= 0,5113, indicating a negligible improvement of 0,0048 in the compliance with the principies of a plural economy. This last result, nevertheless, should be taken with caution, as it is based on the assumption of no improvement of the environmental sustainability indicator during the years 2005 to 2007.

    The availability of updated data certainly constrains a current assessment of compliance with the principies of a plural economy.

    However, a simulation exercise can be useful to prove the ability of the indicator to properly measure the progress towards a plural economy.

    Presume a situation in which the Bolivian government improves the income redistribution and enhances the environmental sustainability to a Gini índex of 35 and an ES índex of 85, respectively. Then, if a vector with these valúes were introduced into the inference system, the plural economy indicator would be equal to 0,6653. This valué would certainly support the claim that Bolivia is becoming a plural economy.

     

    V. Conclusión

    The aim of this paper was to propose a plural economy indicator based on fuzzy sets. A complete inference system was designed and membership functions were calibrated to calcúlate the indicator with real and hypothetical data of income redistribution and environmental sustainability.

    Although only two of the ten constitutional PPE were considered, the empirical and simulated outcomes showed that the indicator translates the redistribution and sustainability indicators to an overall measure of the plurality of the Bolivian economy. Further research is needed to extend the model with the remaining constitutional principies and with measures of the different forms of economic organization. (For example, the WorldBank'sStrengthofLegalRightsInctexcould be usedtoaccount for the principie of legal certainty, and the Transparency International's Corruption Perception Index may be a suitable approximation for the principie oí transparency.)

    Based on the available data of redistribution and sustainability, the results of the plural economy indicator suggested a low compliance with the PPE in Bolivia in the year 2005. The lack of updated data for the year 2011 constrained the possibility to evalúate whetherthe socialist government has actually attained improvements towards a more pluralistic economy in Bolivia.6 However, if new data of redistribution and sustainability became available, the indicator proposed in this study can be used to measure quantitatively the compliance with the principies of a plural economy, and thus objectively judge the effect of the economic changes in Bolivia.

     

    NOTAS

    * The author thanks the editorial review and the comments from three anonymous referees. The usual disclaimer holds.

    1 New Constitution of the State, Part Four (Economic Structure and Organization of the State), Title I (Economic Organization of the State), Chapter One (General Dispositions), Article 306.

    2    Zadeh (2012) defines precisiation as the construction of computational/mathematical models of words, phrases, propositions, questions and other types of semantic entities.

    3    The history of fuzzy logic can be traced back to the Bertrand Rusell's opinión on the Cretans paradox. In the year 1920, Lukasiewicz worked out a multivalued logic in which statements can take on fractional valúes between the 'ones and zeros' of binary logic. In 1973, quantum philosopher Max Black drew the first fuzzy set curves, and almost 30years later Zadeh worked out a complete algebra for fuzzy sets on a paper called "fuzzy sets", term that gave name to this field. Fuzzy logic was popularized by the use of fuzzy sets in Japan to control systems. In 1988, Hitachi turned over control of a subway in Sendai, Japan, to a fuzzy system. In 1992, the Ministry of International Trade and Industry estimated that Japan produced about $2 billion worth of fuzzy produets (Kosko and Isaka, 1993).

    4    In Bolivia, the use of fuzzy logic is almost nil; the only reference that the author found is Aviles (2009).

    5    This section is based on Bojadziev and Bojadziev (2007), Sivanandam et al. (2007), and Guney and Sarikaya (2009).

    6 Two policies of income redistribution of the Bolivian government were (/) the conditional cash transfers Renta Dignidad, Juancito Pinto, Juana Azurduy, and (//) the access to productive capital through the second-tier bank BDP (Banco de Desarrollo Productivo). If these policies make the income redistribution more equitable, this should be reflected as improvements in the plural economy indicator.

     

    References

    Andriantiatsaholiniaina, L, V. Kouikoglou, Y. Phillis, (2004). "Evaluating strategies for sustainable development: fuzzy logic reasoning and sensitivity analysis", Ecological Economics, 48, pp. 149-172.        [ Links ]

    Aviles, J.C., (2009). "El Control Difuso de Temperatura de una Incubadora", Documento de proyecto presentado en las XXII Jornadas en Ingeniería Eléctrica y Electrónica, Universidad Mayorde San Andrés.        [ Links ]

    Bojadziev, G. and M. Bojadziev (2007). Fuzzy Logic for Business, Finance and Management, Advances in Fuzzy Systems - Applications and Theory, Volume 23, Second Edition, World Scientific Publishing Co. Pte. Ltd., Singapore.        [ Links ]

    Bollen J., H. Mao, X.J. Zeng (2011). "Twitter mood predicts the stock market", Journal of Computational Science, 2(1), pp. 1-8.        [ Links ]

    Bresser-Pereira, L. C, (2010). "Fora modestand heterodoxmainstream economics", Paper presented in the Coimbra conference 2010 The Revival of Political Economy - Prospects for a Sustainable Provisión, sponsored by the Faculty of Economics of Coimbra University, October 21-23,2010.        [ Links ]

    Castignani, M.I., M.C. Arregui, N.S. Pelatti (2004). "Estimación de Contaminación por Plaguicidas con Indicadores Ambientales y Económicos en Huertas de Tomate en Santa Fé", Revista FAVE de Ciencias Agrarias, 3 (1-2), pp. 87-94.        [ Links ]

    Chiappero-Martinetti E., (2000). "A Multidimensional Assessment of Well-Being Based on Sen's Functioning Approach", Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, 108 (2), pp. 207-232.        [ Links ]

    Esty, D., M. Levy, T. Srebotnjak, A. de Sherbinin, (2005). 2005 Environmental Sustainability Index: Benchmarking National EnvironmentalStewardship, New Haven: Yale CenterforEnvironmental Law and Policy.        [ Links ]

    Etxezarreta E. y B. Bakaikoa, (2011). "La participación de la economía social en el ámbito de la dependencia: una aproximación teórica", Centro Internacional de Investigación e Información sobre Economía Pública, Social y Cooperativa (CIRIEC - España), Revista de Economía Pública, Social y Cooperativa, No. 71, pp. 25-48.        [ Links ]

    Evers, A. and J.-L. Laville, (2004). "Defining the Third Sector in Europe", in Evers, A. and J.-L. Laville, (Eds), The Third Sector in Europe, Edgar Edward Publishing Limited, Bodmin, Cornwall, United Kingdom, pp. 11-42.        [ Links ]

    Gaceta Oficial de Bolivia, Constitución Política del Estado, febrero de 2009.        [ Links ]

    García, A., (2011). Las tensiones creativas de la revolución. La quinta fase del proceso de cambio, Vicepresidencia del Estado Plurinacional de Bolivia, La Paz-Bolivia.        [ Links ]

    Guney, K. and N. Sarikaya, (2009). "Comparison of Mamdani and Sugeno Fuzzy Inference System Models for Resonant Frequency Calculation of Rectangular Microstrip Antennas", Progress in Electromagnetics Research B, 12, pp. 81-104.        [ Links ]

    He, M., H. Leung, N. Jennings, (2003). "A Fuzzy-Logic Based Bidding Strategy forAutonomousAgents in Continuous DoubleAuctions", IEEE Transactions on Knowledge and Data Engineering, 15 (6), pp. 1345-1363.        [ Links ]

    Heitzmann, K., (2006). "A New Welfare Mix? Theory and Evidence for the Policy field of Poverty Relief, 4th Annual ESPAnet Conference: Transformation of the Welfare State: Political Regulation and Social Inequality, Bremen, Deutschland, 21-23, November.        [ Links ]

    Kosko, B. and S. Isaka, (1993). "Fuzzy Logic", Scientifie American, pp. 76-81.        [ Links ]

    Litchfield, J., (1999). "Inequality: Methods and Tools". Available on http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTPGI/Resources/lnequality/litchfie.pdf        [ Links ]

    Óstermark, R., (1999)."AFuzzyNeuralNetworkAlgorithmforMultigroup Classification", Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 105, pp. 113-122.        [ Links ]

    Pardo, L, (2009). "Elementos y Desafíos de la Economía Plural" en Semanario Nueva Economía, Año 15, No. 762, del 16 al 22 de marzo de 2009.        [ Links ]

    Phillis, Y. A. and L. A. Andriantiatsaholiniaina, (2001). "Sustainability: an ill-defined concept and its assessment using fuzzy logic", Ecológica! Economics, 37, pp. 435 - 456.

    Sivanandam, S. N., S. Sumathi, S. N. Deepa, (2007). Introduction to Fuzzy Logic Using MATLAB, Springer-Verlag, Berlin Heidelberg.

    Stiglitz, J. E., (2009). "Moving Beyond Market Fundamentalism to a More Balanced Economy", Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 80(3), pp. 345-360.

    Zadeh, L, (2008). "Is There a Need for Fuzzy Logic?", International Journal of Information Sciences, 178, pp. 2751-2779.        [ Links ]

    Zadeh, L, (2012). "Precisiation", Studies in Fuzziness and Soft Computing, 277, pp. 41-72.        [ Links ]